Please wait while we process your payment
If you don't see it, please check your spam folder. Sometimes it can end up there.
If you don't see it, please check your spam folder. Sometimes it can end up there.
Please wait while we process your payment
By signing up you agree to our terms and privacy policy.
Don’t have an account? Subscribe now
Create Your Account
Sign up for your FREE 7-day trial
By signing up you agree to our terms and privacy policy.
Already have an account? Log in
Your Email
Choose Your Plan
Individual
Group Discount
Save over 50% with a SparkNotes PLUS Annual Plan!
Purchasing SparkNotes PLUS for a group?
Get Annual Plans at a discount when you buy 2 or more!
Price
$24.99 $18.74 /subscription + tax
Subtotal $37.48 + tax
Save 25% on 2-49 accounts
Save 30% on 50-99 accounts
Want 100 or more? Contact us for a customized plan.
Your Plan
Payment Details
Payment Summary
SparkNotes Plus
You'll be billed after your free trial ends.
7-Day Free Trial
Not Applicable
Renews May 8, 2025 May 1, 2025
Discounts (applied to next billing)
DUE NOW
US $0.00
SNPLUSROCKS20 | 20% Discount
This is not a valid promo code.
Discount Code (one code per order)
SparkNotes PLUS Annual Plan - Group Discount
Qty: 00
SparkNotes Plus subscription is $4.99/month or $24.99/year as selected above. The free trial period is the first 7 days of your subscription. TO CANCEL YOUR SUBSCRIPTION AND AVOID BEING CHARGED, YOU MUST CANCEL BEFORE THE END OF THE FREE TRIAL PERIOD. You may cancel your subscription on your Subscription and Billing page or contact Customer Support at custserv@bn.com. Your subscription will continue automatically once the free trial period is over. Free trial is available to new customers only.
Choose Your Plan
This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.
For the next 7 days, you'll have access to awesome PLUS stuff like AP English test prep, No Fear Shakespeare translations and audio, a note-taking tool, personalized dashboard, & much more!
You’ve successfully purchased a group discount. Your group members can use the joining link below to redeem their group membership. You'll also receive an email with the link.
Members will be prompted to log in or create an account to redeem their group membership.
Thanks for creating a SparkNotes account! Continue to start your free trial.
We're sorry, we could not create your account. SparkNotes PLUS is not available in your country. See what countries we’re in.
There was an error creating your account. Please check your payment details and try again.
Please wait while we process your payment
Your PLUS subscription has expired
Please wait while we process your payment
Please wait while we process your payment
Monopolies
(100 - Q) is the price according to our market demand curve. This 100 - Q represents the marginal revenue brought in by selling the next unit. However, in order to sell the next unit, we had to lower the price by 1 for all units sold (the demand curve has a slope of -1, so the tradeoff between Q and P is 1 for 1). Therefore, on the margin, we lost 1 unit of revenue for all Q units sold. The marginal revenue is then (100 - Q) - Q = 100 - 2*Q.
To solve for the monopolistic equilibrium, we find the quantity at which MR = MC. Solving:
100 - 2 * Q = 10 => Q = 45
At this quantity, the market price would be 100 - 45 = 55. Assuming no fixed costs, the profits for this firm would be 45*(55 - 10) = 2025. Naturally, this is a vast improvement for the firm over the competitive outcome of zero profits.
So what's wrong with making profits? Certainly, profits are good for the monopolistic firms. The consumers are willing to pay for the goods at the monopoly price. Nobody is being forced to do anything, so we have a system of mutually beneficial exchange with no coercion. I think it would be overstepping our bounds for SparkNotes to say there is something wrong with monopoly power, but the foundations for government intervention in monopolistic markets can be found in welfare analysis.
Let's identify the deadweight loss in the example from the previous section. Let Qm be the output quantity chosen by the monopolist, 45 in this market. Let Q* be the output quantity at which the marginal cost curve intersects the market demand curve. Q* = 90 in this market.
Q* is the socially optimal output quantity. Imagine the firm is trading at a quantity less than Q*. At this point, the marginal cost curve is below the demand curve. In other words, the marginal cost to society is less than the marginal benefit (the demand curve). The society stands to gain by trading at a higher quantity. The opposite is true at quantities greater than Q* (convince yourself of this).
Remember that Qm is no greater than, and most often less than, Q*. If Qm is less than Q*, it is suboptimal. The deadweight loss is the area between the demand curve and the marginal cost curve over the quantities between Qm and Q*. The marginal cost is the marginal cost to society, and the marginal benefit is the demand curve. Over these quantities, the marginal benefit is greater than the marginal cost, so the area between the curves represents social surplus unrealized at the monopolistic equilibrium.
The impact of monopolistic behavior on social welfare varies with the shape of the demand curve. For example, with a perfectly inelastic demand curve, the market cannot help but trade at the socially optimal quantity. However, the monopolist has the power to set prices as high as it pleases (for this reason, many of these industries are regulated, such as suppliers of insulin or water). Therefore, there exists no deadweight loss, but all social surplus is absorbed by the monopolistic firm.
A monopolist's power is determined by its ability to set prices, which relies completely on the demand curve a firm faces. In perfect competition, a firm sees a flat demand curve and therefore does not have a practical choice as to what price to offer. The monopolist's power comes from facing a downward sloping demand curve.
Please wait while we process your payment